It seems prudent to break the subject into three discrete questions, all of which might on their own be considered variations on the subject line, but which are, on reflection, very different.
1. What are the problems of modernity?
If you take people on the right, either outer right or mainstream right, and ask them what are the specific problems with modernity, you will get a surprisingly uniform and well-agreed-upon list of problems. The most ardent reactionary and the most mainstream Republican will probably not actually disagree very much on what are the particularly wretched aspects of life in contemporary America. Open borders. Welfare moochers. Criminals not being punished. Endless propaganda against straight white Christian males. You get the idea.
This is worth pondering. The things which trouble us are a substantial cause of agreement.
2. What would be your ideal solution to fix those problems?
If you took the same range of people, and asked them what kind of governing arrangements they would prefer, they might give you quite different answers. Normie conservatives want a return to the constitution as understood in 1950, or 1920, or 1850, or what have you. Further right republicans might want the authoritarian capitalism of Lee Kuan Yew, or the colonial administration of British Hong Kong. Reactionaries might want an absolute monarch, or Moldbug's sovereign corporations.
If you took the same range of people, and asked them what kind of governing arrangements they would prefer, they might give you quite different answers. Normie conservatives want a return to the constitution as understood in 1950, or 1920, or 1850, or what have you. Further right republicans might want the authoritarian capitalism of Lee Kuan Yew, or the colonial administration of British Hong Kong. Reactionaries might want an absolute monarch, or Moldbug's sovereign corporations.
And yet, among the more thoughtful ones, even if they disagreed on exactly what was their preferred model, they would probably also take any other right-winger's governing arrangements over the status quo, if it could actually be achieved. In other words, we might haggle over the ordering, but any of them would likely be an improvement. If agreeing to this were all it took to get it to actually happen, we'd have a reasonable shot at all being on board.
3. How do we get to there from here?
3. How do we get to there from here?
A.K.A. What should we actually do about all this? And on this question, people come to all sorts of answers. I think the reason is that nobody really knows. I tend to believe the Moldbug point that activist strategies are a disaster for the right (see, for instance, Charlottesville). But this is very different from knowing what will work, or even might work. I don't honestly have a great idea, but I'm working on it. When it comes to things like voting, we can't even agree on which direction the sign goes.
To see how wild the divergence can be between the first point (agreeing on current problems) and the third (what to do to concretely improve things), consider the following description of leftism. See if it rings true:
Almost everyone will agree that we live in a deeply troubled society. One of the most widespread manifestations of the craziness of our world is leftism, so a discussion of the psychology of leftism can serve as an introduction to the discussion of the problems of modern society in general.
But what is leftism? During the first half of the 20th century leftism could have been practically identified with socialism. Today the movement is fragmented and it is not clear who can properly be called a leftist. When we speak of leftists in this article we have in mind mainly socialists, collectivists, “politically correct” types, feminists, gay and disability activists, animal rights activists and the like. But not everyone who is associated with one of these movements is a leftist. What we are trying to get at in discussing leftism is not so much movement or an ideology as a psychological type, or rather a collection of related types.
Leftists tend to hate anything that has an image of being strong, good and successful. They hate America, they hate Western civilization, they hate white males, they hate rationality. The reasons that leftists give for hating the West, etc. clearly do not correspond with their real motives. They SAY they hate the West because it is warlike, imperialistic, sexist, ethnocentric and so forth, but where these same faults appear in socialist countries or in primitive cultures, the leftist finds excuses for them, or at best he GRUDGINGLY admits that they exist; whereas he ENTHUSIASTICALLY points out (and often greatly exaggerates) these faults where they appear in Western civilization. Thus it is clear that these faults are not the leftist’s real motive for hating America and the West. He hates America and the West because they are strong and successful.
Sounds pretty reasonable, right?
So what do you think the guy who wrote this proposed to do to fix this problem?
As it turns out, the completely bonkers answer was to send home made bombs to try to blow up a random computer store owner, geneticist, biologist, computer scientist, and a bunch of others. The quote is from the Unabomber manifesto. He's actually one of the few exceptions to point 2 - I wouldn't actually prefer to live in his entirely pre-industrial-revolution society, even if I can agree on some of what has been lost. It's actually worth reading, if for no other reason than the whiplash disconnect between the quite incisive observations he makes about the problems of modernity, and the absolutely insane things he did that made him famous:
Step 1. Send home-made bombs to random people who do things somehow associated with modernity
Step 2. ????
Step 3. Profit!
Step 4. Worldwide revolution where technology is abolished.
That said, I think the widespread agreement on point 2 is, in many ways, equally surprising. Because it's not obvious that we should necessarily find some kind of consensus improvement just because we dislike the status quo. And moreover, it suggests that there actually might be something common to all these alternative governing arrangements that would make them an improvement. Why exactly, do we all instinctively support a lot of each others' solutions?
I think there is a value in trying to condense down a description of what it is at a high level we want. Partly, this is because even if one dislikes voting, one can't get around having to convince people somehow. Maybe not the general public, maybe just the elites. Fine. But also as an important intellectual exercise of understanding what the actual problem with the status quo is. What is it that unites Singaporean authoritarianism, British Hong Kong, absolute monarchy, and sovereign corporations, but isn't present in modern democratic states?
The shortest answer I have, which I think can be given in a lot of different settings without offending people, is this.
Well-defined and secure property rights in the state itself.
You want to know what I want? That's what I want.
Who owns the state? And in whose interest is it to be run? Not some b.s. answer like "the people". Which people, specifically, and in which proportion? What exactly is the decision-making process? How are the cash flows going to be distributed?
That's what's so appealing about sovereign corporations. Not only is there one answer, but everybody knows that answer, and everybody pretty much has incentives to continue to respect that answer. Who owns Microsoft? Not "the people", that's for sure. And in a sense, does it matter who specifically owns Microsoft? Not really. What matters is the structure and the incentives. If the shares all changed hands tomorrow, would you expect Microsoft to act very differently? No. The shares will change hands tomorrow, and you won't even bother to think about it when you load up Windows.
That's what's so appealing about sovereign corporations. Not only is there one answer, but everybody knows that answer, and everybody pretty much has incentives to continue to respect that answer. Who owns Microsoft? Not "the people", that's for sure. And in a sense, does it matter who specifically owns Microsoft? Not really. What matters is the structure and the incentives. If the shares all changed hands tomorrow, would you expect Microsoft to act very differently? No. The shares will change hands tomorrow, and you won't even bother to think about it when you load up Windows.
But if we all agree that Lee Kuan Yew owns the state, or that the British Civil Service with their well-defined system of promotions and personnel owns the state, or that Louis XIV owns the state, that's probably fine as well. If they really truly own it, they probably will have sufficient incentives to run it decently well. They might screw it up - this is why I generally prefer sovereign corporations to absolute monarchy, because regression to the mean and bad genetic draws periodically produces fools at the top. But if they do, they'll be hurt themselves, which probably gives them incentives to hire or consult someone who understands statecraft properly.
A completely well-defined and secure set of state property rights is probably itself a Platonic ideal that can't actually be achieved. Specifying exactly why the individual soldier or policeman carries out the order in every situation, or where exactly the King/CEO's advisors come from, will always be thorny. But we can probably still rank order different arrangements in terms of approximate stability and agreement on state ownership.
A completely well-defined and secure set of state property rights is probably itself a Platonic ideal that can't actually be achieved. Specifying exactly why the individual soldier or policeman carries out the order in every situation, or where exactly the King/CEO's advisors come from, will always be thorny. But we can probably still rank order different arrangements in terms of approximate stability and agreement on state ownership.
Why do we want well-defined and secure property rights in the state?
Because a stationary bandit is better than roving bandits.
When you have one bandit, you get expropriated efficiently. When you get multiple bandits, it turns out like the descriptions in one of the War Nerd podcasts of what it was like to have armies coming over your area during the Thirty Years War. Even if they were just passing through, they had to resupply. So they'd come by, steal all your grain, use your furniture as firewood, perhaps rape a daughter or two, and then camp for the night. Then a few months later, another army would do the same, except they'd be annoyed that the first guys had taken most of the good stuff.
Strikingly, in Brecher's recount, it made surprisingly little difference whether the army was notionally friendly to the country in question, or notionally hostile. Either way, you were getting everything taken. It didn't matter if they were taking next year's seed grain, or you didn't have enough to survive the winter. That's your problem.
Such accounts also show the risk of being hyperbolic. In modernity, we aren't getting randomly mobbed as a society in anything like the way peasants were in the Thirty Years War. Why not?
Well, in the modern west what we have isn't several groups of roving bandits. That indeed would be worse. When the bandits are entirely an outside force, and one that will only be here temporarily, you get absolute catastrophe, and they'll take everything. Rather, we have internal banditry by unstable coalition. None of the bandits are individually strong enough to rob you, but collectively they are. The good news is, the bandits are part of the society themselves, so they're here for a while at least. The other good news is that they (so far, and on average) view their coalition as kinda sorta stable - enough that they can exploit semi efficiently the various groups they eating. And, so far at least, they're smart enough to figure out a way to do that. This is why modern America is grim in many respects, but you'd never confuse it with Mugabe's Zimbabwe, or a the Holy Roman Empire when the Swedish army paid a visit. In a modern context, neither stable coalitions not semi-intelligent leaders exist, for instance, in modern South Africa. Unsurprisingly, it's rapidly going down the toilet. My predictions on that have been correct for as long as I've been writing. If any of my readers are working for the South African tourism board, I suggest the slogan "See it before it's gone", or if you're more optimistic, "See it before it gets worse".
It's still approximately the same group on top over time, or at least there's a fair degree of overlap, which is why the modern west isn't a total disaster. But who exactly is on top, and who is getting more of the spoils, and who is at risk of being cast out altogether - those things are much less stable.
Hence the need for endless political propaganda, because the coalition needs to signal out-group hatred to keep itself together. Hence the ever shifting potpourri of fashionable causes competing for attention, because the relative ownership stakes in the coalition aren't well defined. Hence the endless insistence on public assent to obvious lies, because you need credible litmus tests to determine loyalty. Hence the need to keep bringing in foreign electoral ringers, because some of the important organs of power are still laundered through our four year American Idol contest, and there's the risk that some of the yokels might get uppity.
The best summary of the theoretical solution to all this is still Moldbug's first post on Formalism. Find out who already owns the state, and give it to them officially. That way you only have one hard problem to solve (find out who owns the state), not two (expropriate the existing owners and give it to some new set of stable owners)
The problem is that we have no idea how to define properly who owns the state, because the answer keeps changing. There's also a problem that people who think they should own the state but currently don't may not assent to formalising the current ownership arrangements. And overconfidence makes everyone think they'll get more in the next round of coalition rearranging.
But a whole lot of us instinctively seem to see the appeal in systems where that problem has been solved somehow. Anyhow. King Charles II, Emperor Bill Gates, or the dispersed shareholders in the Disney Company. It doesn't matter much to me. I'll take any of them.
So we're still somewhat back at the problem of point 3. How do we move towards a system where property rights in the state are well-defined?
I don't know, exactly.
But at least I have a more concrete idea of what I'm aiming at, and what might achieve it, rather than having to split the difference between Catholic Integralism and Sovereign Corporations.
And it's phrased at a sufficiently high level of generality that you can say it at a dinner party and not immediately get thrown out.
Maybe that's something. Maybe it's not.
Nobody said point 3 would be easy, or even solvable at all.
Strikingly, in Brecher's recount, it made surprisingly little difference whether the army was notionally friendly to the country in question, or notionally hostile. Either way, you were getting everything taken. It didn't matter if they were taking next year's seed grain, or you didn't have enough to survive the winter. That's your problem.
Such accounts also show the risk of being hyperbolic. In modernity, we aren't getting randomly mobbed as a society in anything like the way peasants were in the Thirty Years War. Why not?
Well, in the modern west what we have isn't several groups of roving bandits. That indeed would be worse. When the bandits are entirely an outside force, and one that will only be here temporarily, you get absolute catastrophe, and they'll take everything. Rather, we have internal banditry by unstable coalition. None of the bandits are individually strong enough to rob you, but collectively they are. The good news is, the bandits are part of the society themselves, so they're here for a while at least. The other good news is that they (so far, and on average) view their coalition as kinda sorta stable - enough that they can exploit semi efficiently the various groups they eating. And, so far at least, they're smart enough to figure out a way to do that. This is why modern America is grim in many respects, but you'd never confuse it with Mugabe's Zimbabwe, or a the Holy Roman Empire when the Swedish army paid a visit. In a modern context, neither stable coalitions not semi-intelligent leaders exist, for instance, in modern South Africa. Unsurprisingly, it's rapidly going down the toilet. My predictions on that have been correct for as long as I've been writing. If any of my readers are working for the South African tourism board, I suggest the slogan "See it before it's gone", or if you're more optimistic, "See it before it gets worse".
It's still approximately the same group on top over time, or at least there's a fair degree of overlap, which is why the modern west isn't a total disaster. But who exactly is on top, and who is getting more of the spoils, and who is at risk of being cast out altogether - those things are much less stable.
Hence the need for endless political propaganda, because the coalition needs to signal out-group hatred to keep itself together. Hence the ever shifting potpourri of fashionable causes competing for attention, because the relative ownership stakes in the coalition aren't well defined. Hence the endless insistence on public assent to obvious lies, because you need credible litmus tests to determine loyalty. Hence the need to keep bringing in foreign electoral ringers, because some of the important organs of power are still laundered through our four year American Idol contest, and there's the risk that some of the yokels might get uppity.
The best summary of the theoretical solution to all this is still Moldbug's first post on Formalism. Find out who already owns the state, and give it to them officially. That way you only have one hard problem to solve (find out who owns the state), not two (expropriate the existing owners and give it to some new set of stable owners)
The problem is that we have no idea how to define properly who owns the state, because the answer keeps changing. There's also a problem that people who think they should own the state but currently don't may not assent to formalising the current ownership arrangements. And overconfidence makes everyone think they'll get more in the next round of coalition rearranging.
But a whole lot of us instinctively seem to see the appeal in systems where that problem has been solved somehow. Anyhow. King Charles II, Emperor Bill Gates, or the dispersed shareholders in the Disney Company. It doesn't matter much to me. I'll take any of them.
So we're still somewhat back at the problem of point 3. How do we move towards a system where property rights in the state are well-defined?
I don't know, exactly.
But at least I have a more concrete idea of what I'm aiming at, and what might achieve it, rather than having to split the difference between Catholic Integralism and Sovereign Corporations.
And it's phrased at a sufficiently high level of generality that you can say it at a dinner party and not immediately get thrown out.
Maybe that's something. Maybe it's not.
Nobody said point 3 would be easy, or even solvable at all.
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteEdit:
ReplyDeleteI love a good summary of ideas, and this summary of the position of the modern right and neo-reaction is exemplary. That in itself is indeed something.
(The following will be rushed and poorly thought through, but I wanted to get my immediate reactions down)
Your main premise of a common starting point: 'well-defined and secure property rights in the state itself'. If all you're saying is that we need to define power and grant/ensure it's stability, as the guiding principle of good government, I'm not sure I agree; or at least not with this particular formulation. Of course any formulation of government will by definition have power at the top, the nature of that power matters.
Obviously as you make clear in the post, stability is to be valued for its own sake - any stationary bandit is better than many roving ones. But I'm not sure I'm willing to concede power to just any bandit just yet.
I don't care who owns Windows because they aren't trying to teach my young daughter how to put a condom on a banana (to use Jim's expression). I'm a little concerned about Disney. I'm very concerned about the Bio-Leninists, and not just because they are inherently unstable (a mercy!).
Jim is adamant that contrary to what Marxists would have us believe, capitalism (sovereign corporation), though interested in its own stability, is downstream from ideology, and with this in mind I very much care what ideology serves as the framework for the sovereign corporation.
Yes, there are similar factors shared by your Singaporean authoritarianism and an absolute monarchy, that we on the right can agree to support. But I'm not sure I agree that what unites them is unconditional power, or that they are equally commendable for this reason, even if that was the case and we agreed it was a good thing.
There is an idea behind monarchy that speaks to people. People are fascinated by royal families and it's more than just the appeal of the 'strong man'. But 'British Hong Kong' doesn't inspire anyone, doesn't gloss the covers of women's magazines or act as a state idol to galvanize men, regardless how much either may be immeasurably better than western Democracies.
What inspires people in the monarchy is not the power or stability per se, its that they are representations of the idea of the people, as 'a' people, and as People per se: they are archetypes if a people's metaphysics, religion, culture, nation, blood, identity. Vox Day is right on this point: there is no Western Civilization, past or future, without the Christian tradition.
I could summaries this as something like: power is subordinate to ideology; as the Kshatriyas are to the Brahmin; as the passions are to the intellect. (Note: Brahmin as the Philosopher-King of Plato, not the progressive priest of Jim). Therefore, 'might is right' needs to be subordinate to 'what is just'.
I don't think in 2,000 years of western political and religious philosophy anyone has yet to offer a better solution to the problem of statecraft than Plato himself. His position is as follows (I hate to send you a link, but having read your blog in full I do believe you will profit from the few minutes only it will take to read, and it is far better written than anything I might. And very salient to the topic in question):
http://harpermcalpineblack.blogspot.com/2016/06/platos-tripartite-commonwealth.html
Love to hear your thoughts.
Thanks for the link. Embarrassingly, I haven't actually read much Plato, so I definitely appreciate the summary (and the implicit prod).
ReplyDeleteI think the point about the ideology of the people in charge mattering is a fair one. Optimistically, the hope is that a lot of the craziness of the current system is a response to holiness spirals that themselves come from insecure power. But this is also a bit of a kludgy answer. I think when the ruler and owner is an individual, then there's a lot more scope for idiosyncratic, value-destroying preferences (e.g. I want to impregnate every woman in the kingdom!). The hope is that when you have dispersed shareholders, the only thing they can easily agree on is making more money. For other variants of secure power, there seems to be more scope for things going wrong. I'd still take it over insecure power in general, though, assuming (a big assumption) that it could actually be achieved.
While I definitely agree that non-sovereign corporations in the west are downstream from ideology, it's less clear to me that this is true for a sovereign corporation. I'd expect some catering to what the customers idiosyncratic preferences are, like corporate social responsibility stuff, but nothing like the obeisance to progressivism that woke capital has today.
In some sense, I think of the "what is downstream from what" question as being related to the question of how does one get there. If someone has an awesome idea about how to influence ideology more towards sanity, and power ends up being secure as a consequence, absolutely no objections from me! It seems easier to me to model stable incentives than figure out how to change an ideology, but that might just reflect my training and thinking.
As for British Hong Kong not inspiring anybody - de gustibus non est disputandum, I suppose. It inspires me for being well run. If it had Lord Cromer in charge, I'd be very happy to have him on my magazines. Chris Patton? Yeah, that's a little harder. Prince William sure has his advantages.